D., the mother of my daughter Elikia, was in Kinshasa this past week
on a business trip.
Having read and re-read all the books I'd brought with me in Kinshasa
from the Boston and Washington over the years, I am desperate for
reading materials, as you can imagine, in a city that has no bookshops
or libraries to speak of.
I was hoping to get from D. maybe one or two novels she'd have carried
in her hand luggage. I got instead tons of books--mostly fantasy and
sci-fi trilogies--downloaded from her Amazon/Kindle account directly
into my PC Kindle virtual library (I still don't have an iPad yet).
With Kinshasa's fickle electricity, it's slow reading indeed.
My reading habit is eclectic: I can jump from, say, Niall Ferguson's
The Ascent of Money to a volume of Harry Potter. In the Kindle batch I
got, I started with Suzanne Collins's The Hunger Games Triology for
two obvious reasons: the phenomenal box office the movie version
grossed; and the imprecations it triggered in a memorable movie review
in The New Yorker.
But there's a book D. wanted me to read straightaway: Daron Acemoglu
and James A. Robinson's "Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power,
Prosperity, and Poverty."
Reading the book now--I am currently on page 84 where the historical
example is the DRC, or rather from the Kingdom of Kongo to present-day
post-Mobutu Congo--I realize I wasted my time with The Hunger Games.
I should have started with this seminal work. And if you haven't
purchased this book yet, do the right thing: do it now! It's a
collection and reference book...
This book simply reads like a thriller--what with the treasure-trove
of (often maddening) historical details the authors harness to sustain
their convincing arguments.
The gist of the book is quite simple: a historical qua political
determinism accounting for the "lay of the land" of prosperity and
poverty in today's world.
The authors give short shrift of "theories that don't work," but which
for too long have bamboozled people in trying (and failing) to explain
income and prosperity disparities in the world: 1) the Geography
Hypothesis (Montesquieu, Jeffrey Sachs, Jared Diamond)); 2) the
Culture Hypothesis (Max Weber's "Protestant ethic" for example); or 3)
the Ignorance hypothesis (Lionel Robbins and his economist followers).
If all these theories or hypotheses fail to explain anything, it's
because they can't account for the enduring "institutional legacy" the
mutually exclusive "extractive and inclusive political institutions"
have in determining the prosperity or the poverty of a given nation.
In other words, extractive political institutions beget extractive
economic institutions; and inclusive political institutions beget
inclusive economic institutions.
In the words of the authors,
"To be inclusive, economic institutions must feature secure private
property, an unbiased system of law, and a provision of public
services that provides a level playing field in which people can
exchange and contract; it also must permit the entry of new businesses
and allow people to choose their careers" (74).
Whereas the authors call the opposite of inclusive economic institutions,
"extractive economic institutions [...] because such institutions are
designed to extract incomes and wealth from one subset of society to
benefit a different subset" (76).
This is a radical departure from the newspeak of economic good
governance that is the current ideology of the World Bank and the
International Monetary Fund. Why Nations Fail would also either
invalidate--or validate (a near impossibility in the case of the DRC
(see below)--out of hand so-called elite-centered economic development
projects.
The radical departure here is the precedence political choices (made
by the elites of a nation) take over economic factors in determining
the path to prosperity or to poverty.
And the authors back up their theory with convincing examples: from
Nogales, Arizona (USA) vs. Nogales, Sonora (Mexico); to other examples
worlwide; and down to us here at ground zero of poverty in the Congo,
from the Kingdom of Kongo to post-Mobutu DRC, etc.
In the particular case of the Congo, the Kingdom of Kongo (and its
king Nzinga a Nkuwu) made contact with the Portuguese as early as
1483. The King therafter converted to Catholicism and was introduced
to Western technologies of the wheel and the plow.
But the Kongolese king chose another Western technology instead: the
gun--in order to engage in the lucrative business of slavery:
"The real reason why the Kongolese did not adopt superior technology
was because they lacked any incentives to do so. They faced a high
risk of all their output being expropriated and taxed by the
all-powerful king, whether or not he had converted to Catholicism. In
fact, it wasn't only their property that was insecure. Their continued
existence was held by a thread. Many of them were captured and sold as
slaves--hardly the environment to encourage investment to increase
long-term productivity. Neither did the king have incentives to adopt
the plow on a large scale or to make increased agricultural
productivity his main priority: exporting slaves was so much more
profitable" (60).
The colonial political system came along the same extractive line.
In the case of Congo's Mobutu and post-Mobutu regimes, the authors
point to the impossibility of simultaneity of (or synergy between)
extractive political institutions and inclusive economic institutions
within the same state formation: one set of those has to give:
"Wouldn't it have been better for Mobutu to set up economic
institutions that increased the wealth of Congolese rather than
deepening their proverty? If Mobutu had managed to increase the
prosperity of his nation, would he not have been able to appropriate
even more money, buy Concord instead of renting one, have more castles
and mansions, possibly a bigger and more powerful army? Unfortunately
for the citizens of many countries in the world, the answer is no.
Economic institutions that create incentives for economic progress may
simultaneously redistribute income and power in such a way that a
predatory dictator and others with political power may become worse
off" (83).
As I said, I am still reading the book. But so far, in light of the
theory expounded in Why Nations Fail, the current Congolese political
spiel of "Modernity Revolution" (that would propel the DRC among
emergent economies) sounds hollow to me.
For that kind of revolution to occur, the authors of Why Nations Fail
argue, you need a Weberian strong and centralized State (having the
proverbial "monopoly of legitimate violence") that would impose
uniform constraints, rights, duties, and law upon all citizens
(strong and enduring inclusive political institutions, that is, where
accountability is measurable by citizens' votes that could kick out
politicians from office); and an overnight obliteration of a system
where racketeering elites have so far thrived unimpeded and with total
impunity in the surrounding ocean of universal squalor.
Do Congolese elites have any incentives for what would amount to a
collective mass suicide? I don't think so.
Why Nations Fail is indeed a very depressing read here in Kinshasa...
Friday, 4 May 2012
Why Nations Fail: A depressing read that ought to be a reference book for Congolese politicos
Posted on 09:17 by Unknown
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
0 comments:
Post a Comment